email us

US Transcom
US Transcom

Shahin & Sepehr

Sehaty Foreign Exchange

Advertise with The Iranian

Economy

Oil & foreign policy
Short-term need for cash prompt excuses

February 24, 1999
The Iranian

The ultimate objective in penning "Just pretend we have no oil" was to provoke debate about the debilitating nature of Iran's dependence on revenues from international sale of oil. The essay elicited a range of feedback, some brutally unkind, but most raised issues which are worth exploring further on this occasion.

The original essay had stated that at these ludicrously low international oil prices, Iran might consider preserving its reserves on the theory that "A barrel of oil left in the ground is one saved for future." A number of readers pointed out the impracticality of this idea.

Where an oilfield straddles the international border, the oil is subject to the rule of capture. If Iran's neighbor is pumping, wrote one reader, it is a "pump it or lose it" situation. A comprehensive analysis of the subject notwithstanding, readers identified three general areas where fields straddle the border -- Masjid Suleiman and Iraq's northern wells, the Persian Gulf, and the Caspian region.

A field wholly situated in Iran but near the international border may invite directional or oblique drilling by a neighbor. This is actionable in international law as theft, pure and simple. What poses a greater challenge is the regime governing the exploitation of shared reserves.

This writer is neither an economist nor a petroleum engineer. Yet it would seem reasonable to observe why the axiom "pump it or lose it," if practiced by both sides, would in all likelihood work to the reckless detriment of both parties. First, the practice results in a short-term glut which, in absence of enforceable cartel pricing, will pitch one producer against the other thereby depressing the price for both. Second, the practice dissipates the oilfield's natural pressure thereby causing the premature aging of the field, forcing the producers to resort to various forms of recovery technologies; this eventually drives up the cost of production and sends the buyers to cheaper oil.

Mr. Hashem Farhang is a petroleum engineer. In his comments to he wrote "With the exception of one field in the Persian Gulf, where the reservoir straddles across sovereignty borders between Iran and one of the Emirates, there is no other reservoir even close to other countries' jurisdictions. In the Caspian Sea we may, in future, also run across a possible similar scenario." This raises the intriguing possibility that the Iranian government, which is in possession of the relevant information, may be using this as an excuse to make up in volume of sale the shortfall in revenue because of falling prices.

The management's solution to competitive partisan or uncooperative exploitation of a shared field is called "unitization." The practice leaves the production of the field in the hands of one operator, who exploits the field with the best economic and structural interests of the field in mind, while the parties share in the cost and profits. One reader called attention to the Semnan oilfields being tapped into by the Soviet Union and subject presumably to a few Iran-USSR production sharing agreements. Mr. Farhang also pointed to a field in the Persian Gulf which Iran shares with an emirate and subject to joint exploitation.

No doubt engineering and economics may argue for unitization or production agreements. Yet to replace a policy of "pump it or lose it" with a common exploitation regime is possible only if the parties possess the necessary cooperative spirit and goodwill to enter into a common regime. Mr. Farhang's reminder that in the case of shared reserves Iran "can always make some kind of arrangements" with its neighbor requires a foreign policy toward its neighbors based on mutual trust.

Good and trusting neighborly relations conducive to joint project management rests on respect for the other's territorial integrity, and economic and political independence; noninterference in the affairs of the other; steadfast dedication to peaceful resolution of disputes, and mutuality.

In an atmosphere of mistrust and suspicion, the government seems to favor a "pump it or lose it" policy because of its short-term need for cash and excuses the "pump it" policy anyway on ambiguous geological grounds. In effect, the failure of the government to foster good neighborly relations impedes mutually beneficial exploitation of a shared reserve. The "pump it" oil policy therefore perpetuates, encourages, subsidizes and finances failures in foreign policy. This observation holds true and applies equally to Iran and any other neighboring country seized by its peculiar brand of myopia.

The poverty engendered by a questionable foreign policy may be overcome some time in the future; the oil squaddered presently for reasons of a questionable foreign policy will be lost forever. For each and both reasons one would be all the more improvished.

The author

Guive Mirfendereski is an international lawyer and adjunct professor of law at Brandeis University.

- Send a comment to the writer
- Send a comment for The Iranian letters section


Copyright © 1997 Abadan Publishing Co. All Rights Reserved. May not be duplicated or distributed in any form

 MIS Internet Services

Web Site Design by
Multimedia Internet Services, Inc

 GPG Internet server

Internet server by
Global Publishing Group.